Default in Russia in 1998

Default in Russia in 1998

After six years of economic reform in Russia privatization and macroeconomic stabilization had experienced some limited success. Yet in August 1998 after recording its first year of positive economic growth since the fall of the Soviet Union Russia was forced to default on its sovereign debt devalue the ruble and declare a suspension of payments by commercial banks to foreign creditors. What caused the Russian economy to face a financial crisis after so much had been accomplished?

1996 and 1997. Optimism and Reform. In April 1996 Russian officials began negotiations to reschedule the payment of foreign debt inherited from the former Soviet Union. The negotiations to repay its sovereign debt were a major step toward restoring investor confidence. On the surface 1997 seemed poised to be a turning point toward economic stability.

• The trade surplus was moving toward a balance between exports and imports.

• Relations with the West were promising: the World Bank was prepared to provide expanded assistance of $2 to $3 billion per year and the International Monetary Fund (IMF) continued to meet with Russian officials and provide aid.

• Inflation had fallen from 131 percent in 1995 to 22 percent in 1996 and 11 percent in 1997

• Output was recovering slightly. A narrow exchange rate band was in place keeping the exchange rate between 5 and 6 rubles to the dollar.

• And oil one of Russia’s largest exports was selling at $23 per barrel—a high price by recent standards. (Fuels made up more than 45 percent of Russia’s main export commodities in 1997.)

In September 1997 Russia was allowed to join the Paris Club of creditor nations after rescheduling the payment of over $60 billion in old Soviet debt to other governments. Another agreement for a 23-year debt repayment of $33 billion was signed a month later with the London Club. Analysts predicted that Russia’s credit ratings would improve allowing the country to borrow less expensively. Limitations on the purchase of government securities by nonresident investors were removed promoting foreign investment in Russia. By late 1997 roughly 30 percent of the GKO (a short-term government bill) market was accounted for by nonresidents. The economic outlook appeared optimistic as Russia ended 1997 with reported economic growth of 0. 8 percent. Revenue Investment and Debt. Despite the prospects for optimism problems remained. On average real wages were less than half of what they were in 1991 and only about 40 percent of the work force was being paid in full and on time. Per capita direct foreign investment was low and regu regulation of the natural monopolies was still difficult due to unrest in the Duma Russia’s lower house of Parliament. Another weakness in the Russian economy was low tax collection which caused the public sector deficit to remain high. The majority of tax revenues came from taxes that were shared between the regional and federal governments which fostered competition among the different levels of government over the distribution.

According to Shleifer and Treisman (2000) this kind of tax sharing can result in conflicting incentives for regional governments and lead them to help firms conceal part of their taxable profit from the federal government in order to reduce the firms’ total tax payments. In return the firm would then make transfers to the accommodating regional government. This Shleifer and Treisman suggest may explain why federal revenues dropped more rapidly than regional revenues. Also the Paris Club’s recognition of Russia as a creditor nation was based upon questionable qualifications. One-fourth of the assets considered to belong to Russia were in the form of debt owed to the former Soviet Union by countries such as Cuba Mongolia and Vietnam. Recognition by the Paris Club was also based on the old completely arbitrary official Soviet exchange rate of approximately 0. 6 rubles to the dollar (the market exchange rate at the time was between 5 and 6 rubles to the dollar).

The improved credit ratings Russia received from its Paris Club recognition were not based on an improved balance sheet. Despite this restrictions were eased and lifted and Russian banks began borrowing more from foreign markets increasing their foreign liabilities from 7 percent of their assets in 1994 to 17 percent in 1997. Meanwhile Russia anticipated growing debt payments in the coming years when early credits from the IMF would come due. Policymakers faced decisions to decrease domestic borrowing and increase tax collection because interest payments were such a large percentage of the federal budget.

In October 1997 the Russian government was counting on 2 percent economic growth in 1998 to compensate for the debt growth. Unfortunately events began to unfold that would further strain Russia’s economy; instead of growth in 1998 real GDP declined 4. 9 percent. The Asian Crisis. A few months earlier in the summer of 1997 countries in the Pacific Rim experienced currency crises similar to the one that eventually affected Russia. In November 1997 after the onset of this East Asian crisis the ruble came under speculative attack. The Central Bank of Russia (CBR) defended the currency losing nearly $6 billion (U. S. dollars) in foreign-exchange reserves. At the same time non-resident holders of short-term government bills (GKOs) signed forward contracts with the CBR to exchange rubles for foreign currency which enabled them to hedge exchange rate risk in the interim period. 7 According to Desai (2000) they did this in anticipation of the ruble losing value as Asian currencies had. Also a substantial amount of the liabilities of large Russian commercial banks were off-balance-sheet consisting mostly of forward contracts signed with foreign investors. Net obligations of Russian banks for such contracts were estimated to be at least $6 billion by the first half of 1998.

Then another blow was dealt to the Russian economy: in December 1997 the prices of oil and nonferrous metal up to two-thirds of Russia’s hard-currency earnings began to drop. 1998 Government Risk and Expectations. With so many uncertainties in the Russian economy investors turned their attention toward Russian default risk. To promote a stable investment environment in February 1998 the Russian government submitted a new tax code to the Duma with fewer and more efficient taxes. The new tax code was approved in 1998 yet some crucial parts that were intended to increase federal revenue were ignored. Russian officials sought IMF funds but agreements could not be reached. By late March the political and economic situation had become more dire and on March 23 President Yeltsin abruptly fired his entire government including Prime Minister Viktor Chernomyrdin. In a move that would challenge investor confidence even further Yeltsin appointed 35-year-old Sergei Kiriyenko a former banking and oil company executive who had been in government less than a year to take his place. While fears of higher interest rates in the United States and Germany made many investors cautious tensions rose in the Russian government. The executive branch the Duma and the CBR were in conflict. Prompted by threats from Yeltsin to dissolve Parliament the Duma confirmed Kiriyenko’s appointment on April 24 after a month of stalling. In early May during a routine update CBR chair Sergei Dubinin warned government ministers of a debt crisis within the next three years. Unfortunately reporters were in the audience.

Since the Asian crisis had heightened investors’ sensitivity to currency stability Dubinin’s restatement of bank policy was misinterpreted to mean that the Bank was considering a devaluation of the ruble. In another public relations misunderstanding Kiriyenko stated in an interview that tax revenue was 26 percent below target and claimed that the government was “quite poor now. ” In actuality the government was planning to cut government spending and accelerate revenue but these plans were never communicated clearly to the public. Instead people began to expect a devaluation of the ruble. Investors’ perceptions of Russia’s economic stability continued to decline when Lawrence Summers one of America’s top international-finance officials was denied a meeting with Kiriyenko while in Russia. An inexperienced aide determined that Summers’s title Deputy Secretary of the Treasury was unworthy of Kiriyenko’s audience and the two never met. At the same time the IMF left Russia unable to reach an agreement with policymakers on a 1998 austerity plan. Word spread of these incidents and big investors began to sell their government bond portfolios and Russian securities concerned that relations between the United States and Russia were strained. Liquidity Monetary Policy and Fiscal Policy. By May 18 government bond yields had swelled to 47 percent.

With inflation at about 10 percent Russian banks would normally have taken the government paper at such high rates. Lack of confidence in the government’s ability to repay the bonds and restricted liquidity however did not permit this. As depositors and investors became increasingly cautious of risk these commercial banks and firms had less cash to keep them afloat. The federal government’s initiative to collect more taxes in cash lowered banks’ and firms’ liquidity. 8 Also in 1997 Russia had created a U. S. -style treasury system with branches which saved money and decreased corruption yet also decreased the amount of cash that moved through banks. The banks had previously used these funds to buy bonds. Also household ruble deposits increased by only 1. 3 billion in 1998 compared with an increase of 29. 8 billion in 1997. The CBR responded by increasing the lending rate to banks from 30 to 50 percent and in two days used $1 billion of Russia’s low reserves to defend the ruble.

However by May 27 demand for bonds had plummeted so much that yields were more than 50 percent and the government failed to sell enough bonds at its weekly auction to refinance the debt coming due. Meanwhile oil prices had dropped to $11 per barrel less than half their level a year earlier. Oil and gas oligarchs were advocating a devaluation of the ruble which would increase the ruble value of their exports. In light of this the CBR increased the lending rate again this time to 150 percent. CBR chairman Sergei Dubinin responded by stating “When you hear talk of devaluation spit in the eye of whoever is talking about it”.

The government formed and advertised an anticrisis plan requested assistance from the West and began bankruptcy processes against three companies with large debts from back taxes. Kiriyenko met with foreign investors to reassure them. Yeltsin made nightly appearances on Russian television calling the nation’s financial elite to a meeting at the Kremlin where he urged them to invest in Russia. In June the CBR defended the ruble losing $5 billion in reserves. Despite all of the government efforts being made there was widespread knowledge of $2. 5 to $3 billion in loans from foreign investors to Russian corporations and banks that were to come due by the end of September. In addition billions of dollars in ruble futures were to mature in the fall. In July the IMF approved additional assistance of $11. 2 billion of which $4. 8 billion was to be disbursed immediately. Yet between May and August approximately $4 billion had left Russia in capital flight and in 1998 Russia lost around $4 billion in revenue due to sagging oil prices. After losing so much liquidity the IMF assistance did not provide much relief.

The Duma in an effort to protect natural monopolies from stricter regulations eliminated crucial parts of the IMF-endorsed anti-crisis program before adjourning for vacation. The government had hoped that the anti-crisis plan would bring in an additional 71 billion rubles in revenue. The parts that the Duma actually passed would have increased it by only 3 billion rubles. In vain lawmakers requested that the Duma reconvene lowering investors’ confidence even further. Default and Devaluation. On August 13 1998 the Russian stock bond and currency markets collapsed as a result of investor fears that the government would devalue the ruble default on domestic debt or both. Annual yields on rubledenominated bonds were more than 200 percent. The stock market had to be closed for 35 minutes as prices plummeted. When the market closed it was down 65 percent with a small number of shares actually traded. From January to August the stock market had lost more than 75 percent of its value 39 percent in the month of May alone.

Russian officials were left with little choice. On August 17 the government floated the exchange rate devalued the ruble defaulted on its domestic debt halted payment on ruble-denominated debt (primarily GKOs) and declared a 90-day moratorium on payment by commercial banks to foreign creditors. The Aftermath Russia ended 1998 with a decrease in real output of 4. 9 percent for the year instead of the small growth that was expected. The collapse of the ruble created an increase in Russia’s exports while imports remained low.

Since then direct investments into Russia have been inconsistent at best. Summarized best by Shleifer and Treisman (2000) “the crisis of August 1998 did not only undermine Russia’s currency and force the last reformers from office…it also seemed to erase any remaining Western hope that Russia could successfully reform its economy. ” Some optimism however still persists. Imports trended up in the first half of 2001 helping to create a trade balance. At the same time consumer prices grew 20. 9 percent and 21. 6 percent in 2000 and 2001 respectively compared with a 92. 6 percent increase in 1999. Most of the recovery so far can be attributed to the import substitution effect after the devaluation; the increase in world prices for Russia’s oil gas and commodity exports; monetary policies; and fiscal policies that have led to the first federal budget surplus (in 2000) since the formation of the Russian Federation.

As discussed earlier four major factors influence the onset and success of a speculative attack. These key ingredients are (i) an exchange rate peg and a central bank willing or obligated to defend it with a reserve of foreign currency (ii) rising fiscal deficits that the government cannot control and therefore is likely to monetize (print money to cover the deficit) (iii) central bank control of the interest rate in a fragile credit market and (iv) expectations of devaluation and/or rising inflation. In this section we discuss these aspects in the context of the Russian devaluation. We argue that an understanding of all three generations of models is necessary to evaluate the Russian devaluation. Krugman’s (1979) firstgeneration model explains the factors that made Russia susceptible to a crisis. The second-generation models show how contagion and other factors can change expectations to trigger the crisis. The thirdgeneration models show how the central bank can act to prevent or mitigate the crisis.

Страницы: 1 2